4) HOTELLING PRICES: MOVIE TICKETS Movie theatre firms F1 and F2 are showing the same movie and have located at L1=0 and L2=1, the two ends of a one-mile-long street. On this street there are signposts every 1/5th mile (at 0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, and 1), and there are 100 movie fans unevenly distributed as shown in the diagram below. Each group of fans sits halfway between two adjacent signposts, so there are 10 fans at 0.1, 30 at 0.3, and so on. Each movie fan will buy a ticket from the nearest theatre, but only if the following buying condition holds: v≥p+ tlx – yl, where v is the customer's valuation (or willingness to pay), x is the customer's location, y is a theatre's location, and t/x – y/ is a measure of the physical travel cost from x to y. If both theatres are within a fan group's acceptable travel distance, the fans choose the theatre that maximizes consumer surplus: CS = v − p − t|x − y| = valuation - total cost. Assume that v = 10, t = 10, and F2's price is P2 = 5 in this Hotelling pricing model (that has fixed locations). Assume prices are integers between 3 and 7: Pi = {3,4,5,6,7}, for i = 1,2. a) Find F1's profit (revenue) if it undercuts F2's price by setting price P1 = 3. b) Find F1's profit if it matches F2's price by setting P1 = 5. Find F1's profit if it sets a relatively high price of P1 = 7. - Of the three prices we tested in parts (a)-(c), what is P1*, F1's best response to its rival's price of P2 = 5? We have only analyzed F1's choices of this market. Does F2 charge P2 = 5 in a Nash Equilibrium? HINT: For (P1=7, P2=5) to be a Nash Equilibrium, each price must be a best response to the other. Clearly show that P2=5 generates higher revenue for F2 than the other prices (or that it does not!). 10 fans at 0.1 30 fans at 0.3 20 fans at 0.5 30 fans 10 fans at 0.7 at 0.9 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 8:0 L1=0 1 L2=1

ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
14th Edition
ISBN:9780190931919
Author:NEWNAN
Publisher:NEWNAN
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Question
4) HOTELLING PRICES: MOVIE TICKETS
Movie theatre firms F1 and F2 are showing the same movie and have located at L1=0 and L2=1, the two ends of a one-mile-long
street. On this street there are signposts every 1/5th mile (at 0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, and 1), and there are 100 movie fans unevenly
distributed as shown in the diagram below. Each group of fans sits halfway between two adjacent signposts, so there are 10 fans
at 0.1, 30 at 0.3, and so on. Each movie fan will buy a ticket from the nearest theatre, but only if the following buying condition
holds: v≥p+ tlx – yl, where v is the customer's valuation (or willingness to pay), x is the customer's location, y is a theatre's
location, and t/x – y/ is a measure of the physical travel cost from x to y. If both theatres are within a fan group's acceptable travel
distance, the fans choose the theatre that maximizes consumer surplus: CS = v − p − t|x − y| = valuation - total cost. Assume that
v = 10, t = 10, and F2's price is P2 = 5 in this Hotelling pricing model (that has fixed locations). Assume prices are integers
between 3 and 7: Pi = {3,4,5,6,7}, for i = 1,2.
a)
Find F1's profit (revenue) if it undercuts F2's price by setting price P1 = 3.
b) Find F1's profit if it matches F2's price by setting P1 = 5.
Find F1's profit if it sets a relatively high price of P1 = 7.
-
Of the three prices we tested in parts (a)-(c), what is P1*, F1's best response to its rival's price of P2 = 5?
We have only analyzed F1's choices of this market. Does F2 charge P2 = 5 in a Nash Equilibrium? HINT: For (P1=7,
P2=5) to be a Nash Equilibrium, each price must be a best response to the other. Clearly show that P2=5 generates higher
revenue for F2 than the other prices (or that it does not!).
10 fans
at 0.1
30 fans
at 0.3
20 fans
at 0.5
30 fans
10 fans
at 0.7
at 0.9
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
8:0
L1=0
1
L2=1
Transcribed Image Text:4) HOTELLING PRICES: MOVIE TICKETS Movie theatre firms F1 and F2 are showing the same movie and have located at L1=0 and L2=1, the two ends of a one-mile-long street. On this street there are signposts every 1/5th mile (at 0, 0.2, 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, and 1), and there are 100 movie fans unevenly distributed as shown in the diagram below. Each group of fans sits halfway between two adjacent signposts, so there are 10 fans at 0.1, 30 at 0.3, and so on. Each movie fan will buy a ticket from the nearest theatre, but only if the following buying condition holds: v≥p+ tlx – yl, where v is the customer's valuation (or willingness to pay), x is the customer's location, y is a theatre's location, and t/x – y/ is a measure of the physical travel cost from x to y. If both theatres are within a fan group's acceptable travel distance, the fans choose the theatre that maximizes consumer surplus: CS = v − p − t|x − y| = valuation - total cost. Assume that v = 10, t = 10, and F2's price is P2 = 5 in this Hotelling pricing model (that has fixed locations). Assume prices are integers between 3 and 7: Pi = {3,4,5,6,7}, for i = 1,2. a) Find F1's profit (revenue) if it undercuts F2's price by setting price P1 = 3. b) Find F1's profit if it matches F2's price by setting P1 = 5. Find F1's profit if it sets a relatively high price of P1 = 7. - Of the three prices we tested in parts (a)-(c), what is P1*, F1's best response to its rival's price of P2 = 5? We have only analyzed F1's choices of this market. Does F2 charge P2 = 5 in a Nash Equilibrium? HINT: For (P1=7, P2=5) to be a Nash Equilibrium, each price must be a best response to the other. Clearly show that P2=5 generates higher revenue for F2 than the other prices (or that it does not!). 10 fans at 0.1 30 fans at 0.3 20 fans at 0.5 30 fans 10 fans at 0.7 at 0.9 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 8:0 L1=0 1 L2=1
AI-Generated Solution
AI-generated content may present inaccurate or offensive content that does not represent bartleby’s views.
steps

Unlock instant AI solutions

Tap the button
to generate a solution

Similar questions
  • SEE MORE QUESTIONS
Recommended textbooks for you
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Economics
ISBN:
9780190931919
Author:
NEWNAN
Publisher:
Oxford University Press
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education