Profit is the incentive that drives our market economy. Firms make production, pricing, and hiring decisions based on their quest for profit. But what happens when a firm discovers that it can make dramatically higher profits by stopping production altogether? In December 2000, due to wild swings in the market for electricity, Kaiser Aluminium faced just such a decision.   Kaiser Aluminium had contracted with Bonneville power for all of its electricity needs and found itself in the unique position of being an electricity consumer and, potentially, an electricity reseller. By December 2000, Kaiser faced a difficult decision of continuing its current aluminium production and profit levels, or closing the plant to dramatically increase its profit by simply reselling its electricity.   When making production decisions, firms must consider both their costs and revenues. One important concern for many firms is utility costs. In 1996, Kaiser Aluminium Corporation in Spokane, Washington, entered into a five-year agreement with Bonneville Power to purchase a fixed amount of power at the price of $22 per megawatt hour, with the right to resell any unused electricity back to Bonneville Power at the current market price. Each company took a risk in this arrangement, with Kaiser Aluminium risking the possibility that energy prices would fall, and it would remain locked into an agreement to pay the $22 per megawatt hour, regardless of current prices. Bonneville Power risked the possibility that energy prices would substantially increase, and it would remain locked into an agreement to supply Kaiser Aluminium a set amount of electricity for $22 per megawatt hour, regardless of current prices. In 2001, due to a shortage of e

Microeconomic Theory
12th Edition
ISBN:9781337517942
Author:NICHOLSON
Publisher:NICHOLSON
Chapter12: The Partial Equilibrium Competitive Model
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 12.14P
icon
Related questions
Question

Profit is the incentive that drives our market economy. Firms make production, pricing, and hiring decisions based on their quest for profit. But what happens when a firm discovers that it can make dramatically higher profits by stopping production altogether? In December 2000, due to wild swings in the market for electricity, Kaiser Aluminium faced just such a decision.  
Kaiser Aluminium had contracted with Bonneville power for all of its electricity needs and found itself in the unique position of being an electricity consumer and, potentially, an electricity reseller. By December 2000, Kaiser faced a difficult decision of continuing its current aluminium production and profit levels, or closing the plant to dramatically increase its profit by simply reselling its electricity.  
When making production decisions, firms must consider both their costs and revenues. One important concern for many firms is utility costs. In 1996, Kaiser Aluminium Corporation in Spokane, Washington, entered into a five-year agreement with Bonneville Power to purchase a fixed amount of power at the price of $22 per megawatt hour, with the right to resell any unused electricity back to Bonneville Power at the current market price. Each company took a risk in this arrangement, with Kaiser Aluminium risking the possibility that energy prices would fall, and it would remain locked into an agreement to pay the $22 per megawatt hour, regardless of current prices. Bonneville Power risked the possibility that energy prices would substantially increase, and it would remain locked into an agreement to supply Kaiser Aluminium a set amount of electricity for $22 per megawatt hour, regardless of current prices. In 2001, due to a shortage of electricity in the western US and several 
other factors, the price of electricity began to skyrocket and fluctuate wildly, to more than $50 per megawatt hour in May, to nearly $175 per megawatt hour in August, to nearly $300 per megawatt hour in December.  
Kaiser Aluminium weighed the trade-offs of producing aluminium or reselling energy. Using cost-benefit analysis, Kaiser made a profit maximizing decision. Although the company recognized its opportunity costs, it was convinced that given the volatility of the energy market, it was in a better position to protect itself in the long run by making its difficult decision of stopping the production of aluminium. Although this was a dramatic example, companies face decisions every day that require them to make choices among alternatives. While the corporation, its shareholders, workers, consumers, and local taxing bodies, may disagree about what is the best decision, the profit motive allows our market economy to run relatively smoothly while giving companies the greatest possible freedom to make the decisions that are best for themselves.  

Expert Solution
steps

Step by step

Solved in 4 steps

Blurred answer
Knowledge Booster
Demand and Supply Curves
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.
Similar questions
  • SEE MORE QUESTIONS
Recommended textbooks for you
Microeconomic Theory
Microeconomic Theory
Economics
ISBN:
9781337517942
Author:
NICHOLSON
Publisher:
Cengage
Microeconomics: Private and Public Choice (MindTa…
Microeconomics: Private and Public Choice (MindTa…
Economics
ISBN:
9781305506893
Author:
James D. Gwartney, Richard L. Stroup, Russell S. Sobel, David A. Macpherson
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Economics: Private and Public Choice (MindTap Cou…
Economics: Private and Public Choice (MindTap Cou…
Economics
ISBN:
9781305506725
Author:
James D. Gwartney, Richard L. Stroup, Russell S. Sobel, David A. Macpherson
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning